The recent CMS Undesirable Business Practice Declaration

Insight Life Solutions

By Craig Getz.

Unpacking the unintended consequences of the recent CMS Undesirable Business Practice Declaration

In a recent Undesirable Business Practice Declaration published in Circular 24 of 2021 and gazetted in Government Gazette No 44469 on 23 April 2021, the Council for Medical Schemes announced that certain restrictions would apply to co-payments that medical schemes will be allowed to levy when a member voluntarily chooses not to make use of a network hospital, pharmacy or doctor. As Craig Getz explains in his blog post below, the consequences of this may not be in the best interest of medical scheme beneficiaries – who will likely end up having to pay more for the benefits they already enjoy when the Declaration comes into effect.

Unpacking the unintended consequences of the recent CMS Undesirable Business Practice Declaration

Apricots and Celestials 

Imagine a scenario: you are the procurement officer for a large company that must purchase cell phones for 1,000 employees. There are two cell phone manufacturers; Apricots and Celestials. Both Apricots’ and Celestials’ phones cost R10,000 per device.

You have a budget of R8,000,000. That is only enough to buy cell phones for 800 employees. Consequently, the 800 most senior staff will receive cell phones, and the 200 most junior staff will remain deprived. This is an unfortunate outcome, so you are committed to finding a solution.

You approach Apricot and ask them for a discount. They appreciate your plight but explain that their prices cannot be discounted unless you can guarantee that all your employees will purchase Apricot phones. While this will be a challenge as some employees have a strong preference for Celestials, you consider incentivising employees to opt for Apricots.

As a solution, you suggest that if Apricot discounts their devices, you will apply a R3,000 co-payment for employees who opt for Celestials. This will result in all but the most ardent fans opting for Apricots. Apricot agrees to discount their price to R8,500 per phone.

You have the same conversation with Celestial. They agree to discount their devices to an even better price of R8,000 per phone should you apply a R3,000 co-payment on Apricots. You agree to the deal with Celestial. Well done! This will allow you to source phones for all 1,000 employees within your budget, and all employees have the option to get a phone without a co-payment. They can choose the other phone if they are willing to pay the extra amount.

By channeling your employees towards a specific manufacturer, you were able to secure deep discounts, made possible by the increased economies of scale (through higher volumes), which Celestial now enjoys.

Unpacking the unintended consequences of the recent CMS Undesirable Business Practice Declaration

Medical schemes and providers

Simplistically, this is precisely how medical schemes and provider networks function. Medical schemes negotiate with the various hospital groups, who then compete for increased volumes by presenting discounted tariffs and other value adds.

Medical schemes select the hospital group(s), representing the strongest value proposition to the Scheme and its members, and then channel patients towards these hospital group(s). Co-payments apply when members voluntarily make use of non-network hospitals. By law, medical schemes are prevented from applying co-payments to the involuntary use of non-network hospitals, such as in the event of emergencies. 

Network arrangements have empowered schemes to reduce their contributions by up to 15% (without any reductions in available benefits).  This increases access to care and allows more people to belong to medical schemes.

This is not to say that medical schemes cannot improve how they select network participants and manage networks. 

  • Some Schemes lack the technical capacity required to analyse or benchmark the costs associated with different hospital groups in a robust way. The hospital groups with the highest discounts and the lowest tariffs are not necessarily the most affordable. Affordability is a function of prices, utilisation and quality. For example, a hospital group with lower tariffs but average stay may represent a poor value proposition. Actuarial tools such as the Insight Diagnosis Related Grouper (DRG) are needed to analyse and benchmark costs properly.
  • Some medical schemes have not given sufficient attention to matters other than the cost of care when selecting network participants. Patient experience, healthcare outcomes (the quality of care) and economic empowerment and transformation are important factors to consider when appointing a network.
  • Some medical schemes do not adequately engage with hospital groups and are not sufficiently transparent when selecting network participants. This means that not all hospital groups are given a fair opportunity to participate on networks.

The Council for Medical Schemes (CMS) indicated that it aims to correct shortcomings like these through regulatory changes published in its Circular 24 of 2021. Efforts to foster increased standardisation, fairness, and transparency should be welcomed.

However, CMS also asserted in the same publication the need to limit the co-payments that can be applied to members who voluntarily engage non-network providers. The suggestion is that co-payments should not exceed the discounts offered by network providers. 

An overly simplistic interpretation of this limitation would be that lower co-payments are invariably beneficial to consumers. In our view, however, the limitation will most likely prevent schemes from securing meaningful discounts from network participants. This would make contributions more expensive and reduce the number of people who can afford to belong to medical schemes.

Unpacking the unintended consequences of the recent CMS Undesirable Business Practice Declaration

Why would the Declaration make hospitalisation more costly for medical scheme members?

Consider the cell phone example above. You secured favourable discounts because the manufacturer knew that the cost of exclusion exceeds the cost of discounts. Specifically, Celestial provided a R2,000 discount to secure its status as a preferred manufacturer. On the other hand, Apricot is now the non-preferred manufacturer and would have had to resign itself to reduced sales as employees opt for Celestial to avoid co-payments. If Apricot wanted to prevent this, it would have to write off the R3,000 co-payment (which is analogous to giving a R3,000 discount). Such a large discount would not be economically viable to Apricot.

Now assume that regulations had prevented companies from applying a co-payment, which is more than the discount offered by the preferred manufacturer (which is what the CMS announced in Circular 24 and its attendant Government Gazette). The advantages of being a preferred manufacturer would quickly dissipate, as would the disadvantage of not being a preferred manufacturer. Discounts would soon become a thing of the past.

The non-preferred manufacturer could maintain its market share by announcing that it would write off co-payments (which, in our example, effectively means Apricot would have to discount prices by only R2,000 and not R3,000 because of the imposed limitation). Given that co-payments could no longer exceed the discounts provided by the preferred manufacturer, this is now economically viable. The preferred manufacturer would not experience an increase in market share. The preferred manufacturer would be no better off than the non-preferred manufacturer, and there would be no incentive to continue to offer discounts.

If the preferred provider does not experience the intended increase in market share, the net result would be as follows: 

Why would the Declaration make hospitalisation more costly for medical scheme members?

We can contemplate a medical scheme attempting to negotiate discounts once the Undesirable Business Practice Declaration comes into effect:

Scheme: “If you give us a 20% discount on your tariffs, I can encourage more members to make use of your services and channel volumes to you.”

Hospital: “No, you can’t.”

Scheme: “Of course I can; I will impose co-payments on your competitors to encourage members to make use of your hospital. It is a win-win situation: you will get more volumes, and the members of our scheme will get lower tariffs, which will translate into lower contributions.”

Hospital: “The Undesirable Business Practice Declaration limits the co-payment you can impose on my competitors to the 20% discount you are asking for. My competitors will simply waive the co-payment, and I will be stuck with the same volume of business but at a lower price. I would be foolish to agree to such an arrangement. I bet my competitors will come to the same conclusion if you were to offer the same terms to them. I would rather keep my undiscounted tariffs and my current market share, thank you very much.”

Unpacking the unintended consequences of the recent CMS Undesirable Business Practice Declaration

The Prisoner’s Dilemma

The Declaration gives rise to what game theorists and negotiation experts refer to as a “Prisoner’s Dilemma”. Providers will realise that they would be foolish to offer discounts in anticipation of higher volumes, as the eventual outcome of such discounts would leave them worse off, both individually and collectively. Rational providers will realise that it is in their best interest to cease offering discounts in return for volumes.

Contributions would become increasingly costly, and access would be reduced. Members with limited financial means would be worst affected since they would have to forgo medical scheme cover if they can no longer afford it.

Unpacking the unintended consequences of the recent CMS Undesirable Business Practice Declaration

Procurement should not only consider the cost.  What about quality?

There are many other compelling and non-financial reasons why medical schemes want to levy co-payments that exceed the discounts offered by network providers. Irrespective of the willingness of non-network providers to match the discounts offered by network providers, the Scheme may wish to channel its members to network providers. 

  • Network providers may be associated with superior healthcare outcome.
  • Network providers may be associated with a superior patient experience.
  • Some network providers may have outstanding empowerment credentials.
  • Network providers may be more cost-effective despite higher tariffs noting that cost is a function of both utilisation and tariff.

Restrictions on co-payments are the unintentional enemy of improved healthcare outcomes, patient experience, empowerment, and cost-efficiency. Restrictions on co-payments have the potential to derail the gains, which provider networks have yielded to members. Healthcare providers will also be adversely impacted as membership volumes decrease due to reduced affordability. 

Such unintended consequences of the announced Undesirable Business Practice Declaration are concerning, and we caution that excellent care should be applied when considering any such amendments.


There is a broad range of additional factors which medical schemes should consider when selecting network participants. This includes but is not limited to the quality of care, accessibility, and the development of an increasingly competitive healthcare environment. 


For more information and/or to schedule a discussion, contact: 

Masimba Mareverwa
masimbam@insight.co.za
0836416525

0

0 Comments

Get an email whenever we publish a new thought piece

Topic:

By signing up you consent to our terms and conditions

More from Insight Life Solutions

Email

Subscribe

Email

Subscribe